The Social Future. Lecture 1 of 6.
Rudolf Steiner, Zurich, October 24, 1919:
The social question
should not be regarded as a mere party matter or as a problem resulting from the
personal demands of a few individuals. It has arisen in the course of social
evolution and belongs to the facts of history. One of these facts is the
proletarian socialist movement which has been growing steadily for more than
half a century.
According to our
own views of life or our circumstances, we may regard the conceptions coming to
light in this socialist proletarian movement, either critically or approvingly.
But whatever be our attitude towards it we can only accept it as an historic
fact which must be dealt with as such. And whoever reflects on the terrible
years of the so-called World-War, (World-War I) even though one may feel
compelled to see causes and motives of different kinds for these horrors, must
acknowledge that it is the social demands, the social contrasts which have to a
great extent caused them. Especially now that we are at the end, at least for
the present, of those terrible events, it must be clearly evident to everyone
that over a great part of the civilized world the social question has sprung to
life as a result of the World-War. If the social question has sprung to life as
a result of the World War there is little doubt that it was already concealed
within it.
Now it will be
impossible for anyone to judge this question rightly who regards it from his own
narrow, often personal standpoint as is so frequently done to-day. No one who
cannot widen his horizon to take in the events of human life as a whole is able
to take an impartial view of the social question, and it is just that widening
of our horizon which is aimed at in my book, The Threefold Commonwealth (Die
Kernpunkte der Sozialen Frage).
We must
remember, too, that most people who speak on the social question to-day quite
naturally regard it in the first place as a question of economics; it is even
looked upon purely as a question of food, or, at best, as facts plainly
demonstrate, as one of labor — a question of food and labor. If we are to regard
this question merely in the light of a food and labor question, we must remember
that the human being is supplied with bread because it is produced for him by
the community at large, and that bread can only be produced by labor. But the
manner in which that labor should and must be carried on depends in every
respect upon the manner in which human society or any separate part of it, for
instance a country, is organized. And to anyone who has acquired a wider outlook
on life it will be clear that there can be no rise or fall in the price of a
piece of bread without the occurrence of great, of immense changes in the whole
structure of the social organism. To anyone who observes attentively the manner
in which the individual worker plays his part in the social organism, it becomes
evident that when a man works but a quarter of an hour more or less, this fact
is expressed in the way in which the society of any economic region procures
bread and money for the individual. You see from this, that even if we regard
the social question merely as one of bread and labor, we at once enlarge our
horizon, and it is of this wider horizon in its most varied aspects that I
should like to speak to you in these six lectures. To-day, before going further,
I should like to make a few introductory remarks.
When we survey
the later and very latest history of the evolution of the human race, we soon
find confirmation of what has been so impressively stated by discriminating
observers of social life; of course, this applies only to discriminating
observers. There is a publication of the year 1910 which contains, it may be
said, the best that has been written on this subject and which is the outcome of
a real insight into social conditions. It is the work of Hartley Withers,
Money and Credit, 1910. The author acknowledges pretty frankly that
everyone who professes to deal with the social question at all at the present
day should keep in mind that the manner in which credit, property, and money
conditions figure in the social organism is so complicated as to have a
bewildering effect. If we try logically to analyze the functions of credit,
money, labor, etc., Withers tells us that it is an absolute impossibility to
collect the material necessary to follow with understanding the things which
arise within the social organism. What has been here stated with so much insight
is confirmed by the whole volume of historical thought in modern times on the
social problem, and especially on the social and economic cooperation of human
beings.
What, then, is
really the conclusion at which we have arrived? Since the time when the economic
life of a country ceased, as one might say, to have institutions of an
instinctively patriarchal character, ever since the economic life began to
assume a more complicated form, under the influence of modern technical science
and modern capitalism, the necessity has been felt to consider the economic side
of life scientifically, and to form such ideas with regard to it as are usually
applied in scientific research or study. And we have seen how in modern times
views have arisen regarding national, or political, economy, (Volkswirtschaft)
as it is called, to which the words ‘mercantilistic’ or ‘physiocratic’ have been
applied, views such as those of Adam Smith, etc., down to Marx, Engels, Blanc,
Fourier, Saint-Simon, and on to the present day. What has come to light in the
course of this national-economic thought? Let us look at the school of thought
known as the mercantilistic, or at the physiocratic school of national economy,
and let us examine what Ricardo, the teacher of Karl Marx, has contributed to
the study of national economy. We may also examine what many other economists
have said and we shall always find that these men turn their attention to one or
another particular line of thought in the phenomena of economics. From this
one-sided stand-point they endeavor to arrive at certain laws according to which
the economic life of a nation can be molded. The result has always shown that
laws which have thus been discovered, according to the methods of scientific
thought, can be adapted to some facts of national economy, but that other facts
are found to be too far-reaching for comprehension within these laws. It has
always been demonstrated that the views of those who, in the seventeenth,
eighteenth, and the beginning of the nineteenth century, claimed to have
discovered laws, according to which, the economic life of a nation can be
constituted, were one-sided. And then something extremely remarkable came to
pass.
It may be said
that national, or political, economy has grown to the status of a science. It
has taken its place among the sciences in our universities, and the whole armor
of scientific thought has been brought to bear on the investigation of the
economic aspect of social life. With what result? What is the answer of Roscher,
of Wagner, or others, to this question? They have arrived at a consideration of
economic laws in which they do not dare to formulate maxims or give expression
to impulses capable of actually grappling with and forming the economic life. We
might say that the role which national economy has taken is that of a
contemplative spectator; it has retreated more or less before the activity of
social life. It has not discovered laws capable of molding human life within the
social organism.
The very same
thing is seen in another way. We have seen that men have arisen, large-hearted,
benevolent, humanitarian, with fraternal feelings towards their fellow-men. We
need only mention Fourier and Saint-Simon. There are others like them. Model
forms of society have been thought out by these distinguished thinkers, the
realization of which, they believe, would bring about desirable social
conditions in human life.
Now we know how
those at the present day think concerning such social ideas who feel the social
question to be one of vital importance. If we ask those who may be said to hold
really modern socialistic views for their opinion of the social ideals of a
Fourier, or a Louis Blanc, or a Saint-Simon, they would say: ‘These are Utopias,
pictures of social life through which an appeal to the governing classes is
made: if they would act in accordance with these pictures, many evils of social
misery would disappear. But all such imaginary Utopias,’ it is said, ‘are
wanting in the force needed to inspire the human will, they can never be
anything but Utopias. However beautiful may be the theories put forward, human
instincts — for instance, those of the wealthy classes — will never alter so as
to put those theories into practice. Other forces are needed to bring that
about.’ In short, an absolute unbelief has arisen in the social ideals born of
feeling, sentiment and modern learning which have been presented to
humanity.
This again hangs
together with the general course of events in the cultured life of humanity, as
seen in the development of modern history. It has often been expressly stated
that what we now recognize as the social question is connected in all essentials
with the modern capitalistic organization of economic life, and this, again, in
its present special form, is the outcome of the preponderance of modern
technical science, and so forth. But there are many points to be considered in
this connection and we shall never be able to deal with these unless we take
into account that with the capitalist regime, and with the modern application of
technical science, an entirely new attitude of mind has arisen among modern
civilized humanity. This new conception of the world has produced great,
epoch-making results, especially in the fields of technical and natural science.
But there is another side to it, of which something must be said.
Those of you who
are acquainted with my books will not have failed to observe that I am ready to
do full justice to, and in no wise deny or criticize unfavorably the discoveries
of modern times through scientific methods of research. I fully recognize what
has been done for the progress of humanity by the Copernican world-conception,
by the science of Galileo, the widening of the horizon of mankind by Giordano
Bruno, and much besides. But side by side with modern technical science, with
modern capitalism, a gradual change has come about in the old world conception.
The new conception of the world has taken on a decidedly intellectual, above all
a scientific, character. It is true that some people find it hard to look facts
straight in the face, but we need only recall the fact that the scientific
world-conception which we now regard with pride has gradually developed, as we
can show, out of old religious, artistic, aesthetic, moral conceptions of the
world. These views possessed a certain impelling force applicable to life. One
truth, especially, was peculiar to them all. They led man to the consciousness
of the spirituality of his own nature. However we may regard those old views, we
must agree that they spoke to man of the spirit, so that he felt within himself
the living spiritual being as a part of the cosmic spiritual being pulsating
throughout the world, weaving the web of the universe. In the place of this old
conception, with its impelling social force, giving an impulse to life, another
appeared, new and more scientific in its orientation. This new conception was
concerned with more or less abstract laws of nature, and facts of the senses,
outside man himself, abstract ideas and facts. Without detracting in the
smallest degree from the value of natural science, we may ask: what does it
bestow on humanity, especially what does it bestow on man in order to help him
solve the riddle of his own existence? Natural science tells us much about the
interdependence of the phenomena of nature, it reveals much regarding the
physical constitution of the human being. But when it attempts to tell us
anything about man's innermost being, science overreaches itself. It can give no
answer to this question, and it shows ignorance of itself when it even attempts
to answer it.
I do not by any
means wish to assert that the common consciousness of humanity already has its
source in the teachings of modern science. But it is profoundly true that the
scientific mode of thought itself proceeds from a certain definite attitude of
the modern human soul. He who can penetrate below the surface of life knows
that, since the middle of the fifteenth century, something in the attitude of
the human soul has changed. when we compare it with former times, and is still
changing more and more, and he also knows that the conception of the world which
we find typically expressed in scientific thought has been diffused increasingly
over the whole human race, first over the cities, then all over the land. It is,
therefore, no mere achievement of theoretic natural science of which we are
speaking, but an inner attitude of the soul which has gradually taken possession
of humanity as a whole since the dawn of modern times. It is a significant
coincidence that this scientific world-conception made its appearance at the
same time as capitalism and modern technical culture. Men were called away from
their old handiwork and placed at a machine, crowded together in a factory. The
machine at which they stand, the factory in which they are crowded together with
their fellows, these, governed only by mechanical laws, have nothing to give a
man that has any direct relationship to himself as a man. Out of his old
handicraft something flowed to him which gave answer to his query regarding
human worth and human dignity. The dead machine gives no answer. Modern
industrialism is like a mechanical network spun about the man, in the midst of
which he stands; it has nothing to give him in which he can joyfully share, as
did the work at his old handicraft.
In this way an
abyss opened between the industrial working-class and the employers of labor,
between the capitalist and the working-man of modern times at his machine in the
factory. The worker surrounded by machinery, could no longer rise to the old
faith, the old world-conception with its impulse for life. He had broken away
from it because he could not reconcile it with the actualities of life. He held
to that, and to that only, which had become a part of modern thought, viz. the
scientific conception of the world.
And this
scientific conception of the world, what was its effect on industrial
working-men? It made them feel more and more strongly that what could be
presented to them as a true world conception was mere thought, possessing only
the reality of thought. Anyone who has lived among modern working-men and knows
the direction taken by social feelings in later times also knows the meaning of
a word which occurs repeatedly in proletarian socialist circles — the word
‘ideology.’
Under the
influences which I have just described, intellectual life has come to be
regarded by the modern working-classes as ideology. They look upon the
natural-scientific view of the world as offering food for thoughts only. The old
conception had not only thoughts to give; it gave them something which showed
them that their own inmost being was one with the whole spiritual world, it
confronted them, spirit with spirit. The modern conception had only thoughts to
give and above all, it contained no answer to the question regarding man's real
nature. It was felt to be ideology. In this way a division arose between the
proletariat and the upper classes who had kept the ancient tradition of the
time-honored world-conceptions of the aesthetic, artistic, religious, moral
beliefs of former times. All this the upper classes retained for the
satisfaction of their whole nature., while with their heads they accepted the
scientific explanation of the world.
The masses of
the people, however, had no inclination for the old tradition or sympathy with
it. For them the only reasonable conception of the world was the scientific, and
this they accepted as ideology; it was to them a mere thought-structure. To them
the economic life was the only reality-production, distribution of products,
consumption, the manner of acquiring or bequeathing property, etc. Everything
else in human life-equity, ethics, science, art, religion, these are all as
vapor rising in the form of ideology out of the only reality: the economic life.
Thus among the masses, intellectual and spiritual life came to be looked upon as
ideology. This was the case especially because the leading classes, while they
watched the development of the modern economic life and familiarized themselves
with it, did not understand how to bring intellectual and spiritual life into
the growing complexity of the economic system. They kept to the old tradition of
the intellectual and spiritual life of former days. The masses of the people
adopted the new cultural life, but it gave them no comfort or nourishment for
heart and soul.
A
world-conception such as this, felt as an ideology which gives rise to the
thought that justice, morality, religion, art, science, are a mere
superstructure, a phantom hovering over the only reality, over the conditions of
production, the economic order of things, may form a subject for thought, but it
gives no support in life. However splendid a world-conception such as this may
be in the contemplation of Nature, it leaves the human soul empty and cold. The
fruits of the scientific conception of the world are showing themselves in the
events of social life in our time.
These social
facts cannot be understood, if we only take into account the content of human
consciousness. People may think consciously: “Why speak to us of the social
question as being of a spiritual nature? The truth is that commodities are
unevenly distributed. We want equal distribution.” People think like this with
the brain. But in the unconscious depths of the soul something very different is
stirring. In those depths is stirring that which develops unconsciously, because
from the consciousness nothing can flow which could fill the soul with a real
spiritual content, for from that source can come only what leaves it dead, only
what is felt to be ideology. The emptiness of modern intellectual life is the
first aspect of the social question which we have to recognize; the social
question is in its first aspect a spiritual question.
Since this is
true, since an intellectual life has developed which, for instance, in the
science of economics as taught in the universities, has reached a merely
contemplative stage, and of itself does not evolve principles of social will;
since it is true that the greatest philanthropists, such as Saint-Simon, Louis
Blanc, Fourier, have conceived social ideas in which no one believes; since
everything without exception that arises out of the mind is regarded as Utopian,
that is, as mere ideology; since it is a historical fact that a life of thought
prevails, which gives the impression of a mere superstructure on top of the
economic actuality, which does not really penetrate to the facts and is
therefore felt to be ideology — for this reason the social question must in its
first aspect be treated as a spiritual-cultural question. One question, above
all, stands out before us to-day in letters of flame. How must the human mind be
changed, in order that it may learn to master the social question?
We have seen
that science has applied its best methods to the study of political economy, and
that the result is mere observation without power to reach the social will. On
the soil of modern intellectual life a type of mind has arisen, powerless to
develop national economy as a groundwork for practical social will. How must the
mind be constituted from which a kind of national economy can proceed, capable
of forming the groundwork of a truly social will?
We have seen
that the great majority of people, when they hear of the social ideals of
well-meaning philanthropists, exclaim ‘Utopia!’ and they cannot believe that the
human intelligence is strong enough to master social facts. How must the
cultural life of a nation be constituted in order that people may learn again to
believe that the mind can grasp ideas capable of creating social institutions
which will remove certain evils of social life? We have seen that the scientific
view of the world is regarded in wide circles as ideology. But ideology alone
empties the soul, and generates in its subconscious depths all that we now
observe in the bewildering chaotic facts of the social problem. What new form
can we give to cultural life, so that it may cease to appear as ideology, so
that it may fill the human soul with strength enabling men to work side by side
with their fellowmen in a really social manner?
We thus see why
the social question must be called a cultural question, we see that the modern
intellect has not been able to inspire faith in itself, that it has not been
able to fill the soul with a satisfying content, but that, on the contrary, as
ideology it has desolated the souls of men. In this introduction, treating the
subject historically, I should like to show how out of the circumstances of
modern life, the social question must he felt in its three aspects as cultural,
legal-political, and economic.
Take, for
example, what was said not long ago and has often been repeated by a personage
actively concerned in the political life, in the statesmanship of our day,
himself a product of the intellectual life of the present day.
With a deep
feeling for the social conditions of America in their development since the War
of Secession in the sixties of last century, Woodrow Wilson perceived the
relationship between the political and legal conditions and those of the
economic life. With a considerable amount of unbiased judgment he watched how
the great accumulations of capital have grown in consequence of the complication
of modern economic life. He saw the formation of trusts and of the great
financial companies. He saw how, even in a democratic state, the principle of
democracy has tended more and more to disappear before the secret operations of
those companies whose interest was served by secrecy, those companies which with
their massed capital acquired great power and obtained influence over enormous
numbers of people. He always used his eloquence on the side of freedom in face
of the growth of power arising out of economic conditions. He knew from a
sentiment of true humanity — this must be said how every single human being has
an influence upon the facts of social life, how the social life of the community
depends upon the manner in which each individual matures for the duties of
social life. He showed how important it is for the health of the social body
that in the breast of every human being a freedom-loving heart should beat. He
pointed out over and over again that political life must become democratic, that
power and the means of power must be taken away from the various trusts, that
the individual capacities and powers of every human being who possesses such
must have free access to the economic, social and political life as a whole. He
emphatically declared that his own Government, which he evidently regarded as
the most advanced, was suffering from the prevailing conditions. Why was this?
Because the economic conditions were there: — great accumulations of capital,
development of economic power, surpassing everything in this domain that had
ever existed, even a short time ago. Perfectly new forms of human social life
had been brought about by economic changes. An altogether new form of economic
life had suddenly been brought into being.
These views are
not the outcome of any leaning towards a theory of my own; they are the words of
this statesman, one may say of this ‘world statesman.’ He has declared that the
fundamental evil of modern development lies in the fact that, notwithstanding
the progress in economic matters, the latter have been controlled by the secret
machinations of certain persons, and the idea of justice, of the political life
of the community, has not kept pace with economic progress, but has lingered
behind at an earlier stage. Woodrow Wilson has clearly stated: “We carry on
business under new conditions. We think and legislate for the economic life of
the nation from a point of view long out of date, an antiquated standpoint.
Nothing new has been developed in our political life, in our laws. These have
stood still. We live in an entirely new economic order, while retaining the
out-of-date legal and political ideas.” These are the words, or nearly so,
spoken by Woodrow Wilson himself. In earnest words he demands that the
individual shall work for the benefit of the community, not for his own. He
points out that, as long as the incongruity between the political and the
economic life continues to exist, the requirements of human evolution at the
present epoch in history cannot be satisfied, and he subjects the life of
society around him to a severe criticism.
I have taken
great pains to examine Woodrow Wilson's criticism of modern social conditions,
especially those he has in view, the American, and to compare it with other
criticisms. (I am going to say something very paradoxical, but present
conditions often urgently demand a paradox, in order to do justice to the
realities of our day.) I have tried both as to the outer form and the inner
impulses to compare Woodrow Wilson's criticism of society, in the first place as
criticism, with that exercised by advanced thinkers and those holding radical,
social democratic opinions. Indeed, one may even extend this comparison to the
opinions of the most extreme radicals of the Socialist Party in thought and
action. If we go no further than the opinions of such men, it may be said that
Woodrow Wilson's criticism of the present social order agrees almost word for
word with the sentiments expressed even by Lenin and Trotsky, the
gravediggers of modern civilization, of whom it may be said that, if their rule
continues too long, even in a few places, it will signify the death of modern
civilization and must of necessity lead to the destruction of all the
attainments of modern civilization. In spite of this we must give expression
to the paradox: Woodrow Wilson, who certainly imagined a very different
reconstruction of social conditions from that of these destroyers of society,
directs almost literally the same criticism against the present order as these
others, and he comes to the same conclusion that legal and political conceptions
in their present form are obsolete, and are no longer fitted to deal with the
economic system. And, strange to say, when we try to find something positive and
to test what Woodrow Wilson has produced in order to construct a new social
organism, we find hardly any answer, only a few measures here and there, which
have even been proposed elsewhere by someone much less scathing in his
criticism. But he gives no answer to the question relative to the changes
necessary in legal matters, in political conceptions and impulses, in order that
these may control the demands of modern economic life and render it possible for
them to intervene in its activities.
Here we find
that out of modern life itself emerges the second aspect of the social question,
that of law and equity. A foundation must first be sought for the necessary
legal and political conditions for the State which must exist in order to be
able to grapple with and dominate modern economic organizations. We ask: how can
we attain to a state of rights, to political impulses, which can meet the great
demands of the problem? This is the second aspect of the social question.
If we
contemplate life itself we shall find that the social life of man is threefold.
Three aspects are clearly distinguished in him when we consider him as a member
of human society. If he is to contribute his share, as he certainly must, to the
well-being of the social order in modern society, if he is to add to the welfare
of the community by cooperation, in the production of values, of commodities, he
must first of all possess individual capacity, individual talent, ability. In
the second place, he must be able to live at peace with his fellow-men and to
work harmoniously with them. Thirdly, he must be able to find his proper place,
from which he can further the interests of the community by his work, by his
activity, by his achievements.
With respect to
the first of these the individual is dependent on human society for the
development of his capacities and talents, for the training of his intellect, so
that the educated intelligence in him may become at the same time his guide in
his physical work.
For the second,
the individual is dependent on the existence of a social edifice in which he can
live in peace and harmony with his fellow-men. The first has to do with the
cultural side of life. In the following lectures we shall see the dependence of
the intellectual life on the first aspect. The second leads us into the domain
of equity, and this can only develop in accordance with its own nature, if a
social structure has been established which enables people to work together
peacefully and labor for one another. And the economic aspect, this modern
economic organization is compared, as I have described it, by Woodrow Wilson to
a man who has outgrown his clothes, so that his limbs protrude on all sides.
These outgrown garments represent to Woodrow Wilson the old legal and political
conceptions which the economic body has long since outgrown. The growth of the
economic organization beyond the old cultural and political organizations was
always strongly felt by socialist thinkers, and we need only look at one thing
in order to find the forces at work there.
As we know (we
shall go into all these matters more minutely afterwards), the modern
proletariat is completely under the influence of Marxism, as it is called.
Marxism, or the Marxist doctrine of the conversion of the private ownership of
means of production into public ownership, has been much modified by followers
and opponents of Karl Marx, but Marxism has, nevertheless, a strong influence on
the minds, the views of life, of great masses of people at the present day, and
it shows itself distinctly in the chaotic social events of our time. If we take
up the undoubtedly remarkable and interesting little book by Friedrich Engels,
the friend and collaborator of Karl Marx, Socialism in its Evolution from Utopia
to Science, and acquaint ourselves with the whole train of thought in this book,
we shall see how a socialist thinker regards economics in its relationship to
the political and cultural life of modern times. We must fully understand one
sentence, for instance, which occurs in a summary in Engels's little book:
‘In future there must be no more governments over men, over individuals, but
only leadership by the branches of economic life and control of
production.’
These are
weighty words. They mean that the holders of such views desire that something in
the economic life should cease, something which, following the modern
evolutionary impulses, has become a part of the economic life. The economic
aspect of life has to a great extent over-spread everything, because it has
outgrown both political and cultural life, and it has acted like a suggestion on
the thoughts, feelings, also on the passions of men. And thus it becomes ever
more evident that the manner in which the business of a nation is carried on
determines, in reality, the cultural and political life of the people. It
becomes ever more evident that the commercial and industrial magnates, by their
position alone, have acquired the monopoly of culture. The economically weak
remain the uneducated. A certain connection has become apparent between the
economic and the cultural, and between the cultural and the political
organization. The cultural life has become more and more one which does not
evolve out of its own inner needs and does not follow its own impulses, but
which, especially when it is under public administration, as in schools and
educational institutions, receives the form most useful to the political
authority. The human being can no longer be judged according to his capacities;
he can no longer be developed as his inborn talents demand. But it is asked:
‘What does the State want? What talents are needed for business? How many men
are wanted with a particular training?’ The teaching, the schools, the
examinations are all directed to this end. The cultural life cannot follow its
own laws of development; it is adapted to the political and the economic
life.
The immediate
effect of this tendency, which we have seen especially of late, has been to make
the economic system dependent on the political system. Men like Marx and Engels
saw this union of economics, politics, and culture; they saw that the new
economic life was no longer compatible with the old political form, nor with the
old form of culture. They came to the conclusion that the life of rights, the
old life of rights, and the cultural life must be excluded from the economic
life. But they were led into a singular error of judgment, of which we shall
have much to say in. these lectures. They regarded the economic life, which they
could see with their own eyes, as. the sole reality. The cultural life and the
life of equity they saw as ideology, and they believed that the economic life
could bring forth out of itself the new political, and the new cultural
conditions. So the belief arose — the most fatal of errors — that the economic
system must be carried on in a definitely ordered manner. If this were done,
they thought, then out of that economic system the cultural life, laws,
state-life and politics must come of themselves.
How was it
possible for this error of judgment to arise? Only because the real structure of
human economy, actual labor in the economic system, was concealed behind what is
usually called finance. The financial system made its appearance in Europe as an
accompaniment of certain events. If we look more deeply into history we shall
see that about the time when the Reformation and the Renaissance brought a new
spirit into European civilization, treasures of gold and silver were opened up
in America, and caused an influx of gold and silver, especially from Central and
South America, into Europe. What was formerly an exchange of natural products
was gradually replaced by the financial system. The natural system of economics
could be directed to that which the soil yielded, that is to say, to actuality.
Under this system the capacity of the individual with his productive powers
could be taken into account; that is, his value as a worker and that of the
actual substance of the commodity could be seen in proper relationship. We shall
see in these lectures how, with the circulation of money, the importance
attached to the essential elements in economics gradually disappeared; with the
substitution of finance for the system of natural economy, a veil has, as it
were, been drawn over the whole economic life; its actual requirements could no
longer be perceived. With what does the economic system provide us? With
commodities for our consumption. We need not pause to-day to distinguish between
mental and physical commodities, for the former may also be included in the
economic system and used for human consumption. The economic system, then,
provides commodities and these commodities are values, because the individual
needs them, because he desires them. The individual must attach a certain value
to a commodity, and in this way the latter acquires an objective value within
the social body, and this value is closely connected with the subjective
valuation resulting from the individual's private judgment. But how is the value
of commodities expressed which may be said to represent the importance of these
commodities in the social and economic life? It is expressed by the price. We
shall have more to say later about value and price; to-day I will only say that
in economic intercourse, indeed, in social intercourse generally, in so far as
the buying and selling of products is concerned, the value of the products for
the consumer is expressed by the price. It is a great error to confound the
value of commodities with the money price, and people will find out by degrees,
not by theoretical deliberations, but in practice, that the value of commodities
produced by the economic body and that which is the result of human, subjective
judgment, or of certain social and political conditions, is very different from
all that is expressed in the price and in the conditions created by money. But
the value of commodities has been concealed in recent times by the conditions
governing prices.
This lies at the
basis of modern social conditions as the third aspect of the social question.
People will learn to recognize the social question as an economic question, when
they again begin to give due weight to that which fixes the actual value of
commodities, as compared with all that finds expression in the mere prices.
Price standards cannot be maintained, especially in moments of crisis, except
when the State, i.e. the domain of law, guarantees the value of money, that is,
the value of a single commodity. Without entering into any theoretical
consideration regarding the result of misunderstanding the difference between
price and value, we can cite something which has actually taken place of late.
We read in the literature of political economy that long ago in Central Europe
and until the end of the Middle Ages the old system of natural economy was in
use. This was built up on the mere exchange of commodities, and its place was
taken by the financial system, in which current coin represents commodities and
in which only the commodity value is actually exchanged for money. But there is
something new making its appearance in social life which seems likely to take
the place of the financial system. This new element is everywhere at work, but
it passes unnoticed as yet. Anyone who can see through the mere figures in his
cashbook and ledger, and can read the language of these figures, will find that
they do not merely represent the value of commodities, but that the figures
often express what we may call the conditions of credit in the newest sense of
the word. What a man can do, because someone believes him to be capable of it,
that which can awaken confidence in the man's capacity, this, strange as it may
seem, begins to appear more and more frequently in our dull, dry, business life.
Look into business books and you will find that as against the mere money
values, mutual confidence, belief in human capacity is beginning to be evident.
In modern business books, when we know how to read them, a great change is
expressed, a social metamorphosis. When it is said that the old natural economy
has given place to the financial system, it must now be added that, in the third
place, finance is giving way to credit.
With this change
the place of an old institution has again been taken by something new. Thereby a
new element appears in social life, the value of the human being. The economic
body itself, as far as the production of values is concerned, is on the verge of
a transformation. It is faced by a problem. This is the third aspect of the
social question.
In these
lectures we shall have to learn to look at the social question (a) as a cultural
question, (b) as one of law, of the State or politics, and (c) as an economic
question.
The spirit must
give the answer to the following: How can men be made strong and capable, so
that a social structure may arise without the present evils, which are
unjustifiable?
The second
question is: Under the advanced conditions of the present economic life, what is
the political system or system of equity which can lead men to live in peace
again?
The third is:
What social structure will enable each individual to find the place from which
he can work for the human community and its welfare, as well as his nature, his
talents and capacities permit? We shall be led to the answer by the question:
What credit can be attached to the personal value of a human being? Here we see
the transformation of the economic system out of new conditions.
A cultural, a
political, and an economic problem are all contained in the social question, and
we shall see that the smallest detail of that question can only appear in its
true light when we look at it as a whole, fundamentally, in these three aspects
cultural, legal-political, and economic.
No comments:
Post a Comment